From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
The printable version is no longer supported and may have rendering errors. Please update your browser bookmarks and please use the default browser print function instead.
Type of matrix in linear algebra
In linear algebra , a square nonnegative matrix
A
{\displaystyle A}
of order
n
{\displaystyle n}
is said to be productive , or to be a Leontief matrix , if there exists a
n
×
1
{\displaystyle n\times 1}
nonnegative column matrix
P
{\displaystyle P}
such as
P
−
A
P
{\displaystyle P-AP}
is a positive matrix .
History
The concept of productive matrix was developed by the economist Wassily Leontief (Nobel Prize in Economics in 1973) in order to model and analyze the relations between the different sectors of an economy.[ 1] The interdependency linkages between the latter can be examined by the input-output model with empirical data.
Explicit definition
The matrix
A
∈
M
n
,
n
(
R
)
{\displaystyle A\in \mathrm {M} _{n,n}(\mathbb {R} )}
is productive if and only if
A
⩾
0
{\displaystyle A\geqslant 0}
and
∃
P
∈
M
n
,
1
(
R
)
,
P
>
0
{\displaystyle \exists P\in \mathrm {M} _{n,1}(\mathbb {R} ),P>0}
such as
P
−
A
P
>
0
{\displaystyle P-AP>0}
.
Here
M
r
,
c
(
R
)
{\displaystyle \mathrm {M} _{r,c}(\mathbb {R} )}
denotes the set of r ×c matrices of real numbers , whereas
>
0
{\displaystyle >0}
and
⩾
0
{\displaystyle \geqslant 0}
indicates a positive and a nonnegative matrix , respectively.
Properties
The following properties are proven e.g. in the textbook (Michel 1984).[ 2]
Characterization
Theorem
A nonnegative matrix
A
∈
M
n
,
n
(
R
)
{\displaystyle A\in \mathrm {M} _{n,n}(\mathbb {R} )}
is productive if and only if
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
is invertible with a nonnegative inverse, where
I
n
{\displaystyle I_{n}}
denotes the
n
×
n
{\displaystyle n\times n}
identity matrix .
Proof
"If" :
Let
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
be invertible with a nonnegative inverse,
Let
U
∈
M
n
,
1
(
R
)
{\displaystyle U\in \mathrm {M} _{n,1}(\mathbb {R} )}
be an arbitrary column matrix with
U
>
0
{\displaystyle U>0}
.
Then the matrix
P
=
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
U
{\displaystyle P=(I_{n}-A)^{-1}U}
is nonnegative since it is the product of two nonnegative matrices.
Moreover,
P
−
A
P
=
(
I
n
−
A
)
P
=
(
I
n
−
A
)
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
U
=
U
>
0
{\displaystyle P-AP=(I_{n}-A)P=(I_{n}-A)(I_{n}-A)^{-1}U=U>0}
.
Therefore
A
{\displaystyle A}
is productive.
"Only if" :
Let
A
{\displaystyle A}
be productive, let
P
>
0
{\displaystyle P>0}
such that
V
=
P
−
A
P
>
0
{\displaystyle V=P-AP>0}
.
The proof proceeds by reductio ad absurdum .
First, assume for contradiction
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
is singular .
The endomorphism canonically associated with
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
can not be injective by singularity of the matrix.
Thus some non-zero column matrix
Z
∈
M
n
,
1
(
R
)
{\displaystyle Z\in \mathrm {M} _{n,1}(\mathbb {R} )}
exists such that
(
I
n
−
A
)
Z
=
0
{\displaystyle (I_{n}-A)Z=0}
.
The matrix
−
Z
{\displaystyle -Z}
has the same properties as
Z
{\displaystyle Z}
, therefore we can choose
Z
{\displaystyle Z}
as an element of the kernel with at least one positive entry.
Hence
c
=
sup
i
∈
[
|
1
,
n
|
]
z
i
p
i
{\displaystyle c=\sup _{i\in [|1,n|]}{\frac {z_{i}}{p_{i}}}}
is nonnegative and reached with at least one value
k
∈
[
|
1
,
n
|
]
{\displaystyle k\in [|1,n|]}
.
By definition of
V
{\displaystyle V}
and of
Z
{\displaystyle Z}
, we can infer that:
c
v
k
=
c
(
p
k
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
p
i
)
=
c
p
k
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
c
p
i
{\displaystyle cv_{k}=c(p_{k}-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}p_{i})=cp_{k}-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}cp_{i}}
c
p
k
=
z
k
=
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
z
i
{\displaystyle cp_{k}=z_{k}=\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}z_{i}}
, using that
Z
=
A
Z
{\displaystyle Z=AZ}
by construction.
Thus
c
v
k
=
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
(
z
i
−
c
p
i
)
≤
0
{\displaystyle cv_{k}=\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}(z_{i}-cp_{i})\leq \ 0}
, using that
z
i
≤
c
p
i
{\displaystyle z_{i}\leq cp_{i}}
by definition of
c
{\displaystyle c}
.
This contradicts
c
>
0
{\displaystyle c>0}
and
v
k
>
0
{\displaystyle v_{k}>0}
, hence
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
is necessarily invertible.
Second, assume for contradiction
I
n
−
A
{\displaystyle I_{n}-A}
is invertible but with at least one negative entry in its inverse.
Hence
∃
X
∈
M
n
,
1
(
R
)
,
X
⩾
0
{\displaystyle \exists X\in \mathrm {M} _{n,1}(\mathbb {R} ),X\geqslant 0}
such that there is at least one negative entry in
Y
=
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
X
{\displaystyle Y=(I_{n}-A)^{-1}X}
.
Then
c
=
sup
i
∈
[
|
1
,
n
|
]
−
y
i
p
i
{\displaystyle c=\sup _{i\in [|1,n|]}-{\frac {y_{i}}{p_{i}}}}
is positive and reached with at least one value
k
∈
[
|
1
,
n
|
]
{\displaystyle k\in [|1,n|]}
.
By definition of
V
{\displaystyle V}
and of
X
{\displaystyle X}
, we can infer that:
c
v
k
=
c
(
p
k
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
p
i
)
=
−
y
k
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
c
p
i
{\displaystyle cv_{k}=c(p_{k}-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}p_{i})=-y_{k}-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}cp_{i}}
x
k
=
y
k
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
y
i
{\displaystyle x_{k}=y_{k}-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}y_{i}}
, using that
X
=
(
I
n
−
A
)
Y
{\displaystyle X=(I_{n}-A)Y}
by construction
c
v
k
+
x
k
=
−
∑
i
=
1
n
a
k
i
(
c
p
i
+
y
i
)
⩾
0
{\displaystyle cv_{k}+x_{k}=-\sum _{i=1}^{n}a_{ki}(cp_{i}+y_{i})\geqslant 0}
using that
−
y
i
⩽
c
p
i
{\displaystyle -y_{i}\leqslant cp_{i}}
by definition of
c
{\displaystyle c}
.
Thus
x
k
≤
−
c
v
k
<
0
{\displaystyle x_{k}\leq -cv_{k}<0}
, contradicting
X
⩾
0
{\displaystyle X\geqslant 0}
.
Therefore
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
{\displaystyle (I_{n}-A)^{-1}}
is necessarily nonnegative.
Transposition
Proposition
The transpose of a productive matrix is productive.
Proof
Let
A
∈
M
n
,
n
(
R
)
{\displaystyle A\in \mathrm {M} _{n,n}(\mathbb {R} )}
a productive matrix.
Then
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
{\displaystyle (I_{n}-A)^{-1}}
exists and is nonnegative.
Yet
(
I
n
−
A
T
)
−
1
=
(
(
I
n
−
A
)
T
)
−
1
=
(
(
I
n
−
A
)
−
1
)
T
{\displaystyle (I_{n}-A^{T})^{-1}=((I_{n}-A)^{T})^{-1}=((I_{n}-A)^{-1})^{T}}
Hence
(
I
n
−
A
T
)
{\displaystyle (I_{n}-A^{T})}
is invertible with a nonnegative inverse.
Therefore
A
T
{\displaystyle A^{T}}
is productive.
Application
With a matrix approach of the input-output model , the consumption matrix is productive if it is economically viable and if the latter and the demand vector are nonnegative.
References