Linear utility
In economics and consumer theory, a linear utility function is a function of the form:
or, in vector form:
where:
- is the number of goods in the economy.
- is a vector of size that represents a bundle. The element represents the amount of good in the bundle.
- is a vector of size that represents the subjective preferences of the consumer. The element represents the relative value that the consumer assigns to good . If , this means that the consumer thinks that product is totally worthless. The higher is, the more valuable a unit of this product is for the consumer.
For a consumer with a linear utility function, the marginal rate of substitution of all goods is constant. For every two goods :
- .
Economy with linear utilities
Define a linear economy as an exchange economy in which all agents have linear utility functions. Several economists studied the properties of linear economies.
Existence and uniqueness of competitive equilibrium
David Gale[1] proved necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of a competitive equilibrium in a linear economy. He also proved several other properties of linear economies.
Assume that each agent has an initial endowment . This is a vector of size in which the element represents the amount of good that is initially owned by agent . Then, the initial utility of this agent is .
A set of agents is called self-sufficient if the members of assign a positive value only for goods that are owned exclusively by members of (in other words, they assign a value of to any product which is place no value on the goods owned by agents that are not in
Calculating competitive equilibrium
Eaves[2] presented an algorithm for finding a competitive equilibrium in a finite number of steps, when such an equilibrium exists.
Related concepts
Linear utilities functions are a small subset of Quasilinear utility functions.
Suppose the set of goods is not finite but continuous. E.g, the commodity is a heterogeneous resource, such as land. Then, the utility functions are not functions of a finite number of variables, but rather set functions defined on Borel subsets of the land. The natural generalization of a linear utility function to that model is an additive set function. This is the common case in the theory of fair cake-cutting.
Under certain conditions, an ordinal preference relation can be represented by a linear and continuous utility function.[3]
References
- ^ a b Gale, David (1976). "The linear exchange model". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 3 (2): 205. doi:10.1016/0304-4068(76)90029-x.
- ^ a b Eaves, B.Curtis (1976). "A finite algorithm for the linear exchange model". Journal of Mathematical Economics. 3 (2): 197. doi:10.1016/0304-4068(76)90028-8.
- ^ a b Candeal-Haro, Juan Carlos; Induráin-Eraso, Esteban (1995). "A note on linear utility". Economic Theory. 6 (3): 519. doi:10.1007/bf01211791.