Jump to content

Generalized Ozaki cost function

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Tatsueins60 (talk | contribs) at 01:08, 31 March 2024 (The demand function was derived and its implications were discussed.). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

In economics the generalized-Ozaki cost is a general description of cost proposed by Shinichiro Nakamura.[1]

For a given output , at time and a vector of input prices , the generalized-Ozaki (GO) unit cost function is expressed as

Here, the unit cost represents the cost per unit of output, and By applying the Shephard's lemma, we derive the demand function for input per unit of output (or input coefficient in the input-output (IO) model):

Here, denotes the amount of input per unit of output.

The GO cost function is flexible in the price space, and treats scale effects and technical change in a highly general manner. Some notable special cases include:

  • Homothticity (HT): for all .
  • Homogeneity of (of degree one) in output (HG): in addition to HT.
  • Factor limitationality (FL): for all .
  • Neutral technicla change (NT): for all .

When (HT) holds, the GO function reduces to the Generalized Leontief function of Diewert[2], a well-known flexible functional form for cost and production functions. When (FL) hods, it reduces to a non-linear version of Leontief's input-coefficient model, which explains the cross-sectional variation of when variations in input prices were negligible[3]:

Discussion

In econometrics it is often desirable to have a model of the cost of production of a given output with given inputs—or in common terms, what it will cost to produce some number of goods at prevailing prices, or given prevailing prices and a budget, how much can be made. Generally, there are two parts to a cost function, the fixed and variable costs involved in production.

The marginal cost is the change in the cost of production for a single unit. Most cost functions then take the price of the inputs and adjust for different factors of production, typically, technology, economies of scale, and elasticities of inputs.

Traditional cost functions include Cobb–Douglas and the constant elasticity of substitution models. These are still used because for a wide variety of activities, effects such as varying ability to substitute materials do not change. For example, for people running a bake sale, the ability to substitute one kind of chocolate chip for another will not vary over the number of cookies they can bake. However, as economies of scale and changes in substitution become important models that handle these effects become more useful, such as the transcendental log cost function.

The traditional forms are economically homothetic. This means they can be expressed as a function, and that function can be broken into an outer part and an inner part. The inner part will appear once as a term in the outer part, and the inner part will be monotonically increasing, or to say it another way, it never goes down. However, empirically in the areas of trade and production, homoethetic and monolithic functional models do not accurately predict results. One example is in the gravity equation for trade, or how much will two countries trade with each other based on GDP and distance. This led researchers to explore non-homothetic models of production, to fit with a cross section analysis of producer behavior, for example, when producers would begin to minimize costs by switching inputs or investing in increased production.

See also

Production function

List of production functions

Constant elasticity of substitution

Shephard's lemma

Returns to scale

References

  1. ^ Shinichiro Nakamura (1990). "A Nonhomothetic Generalized Leontief Cost Function Based on Pooled Data". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 72 (4). The MIT Press: 649–656. doi:10.2307/2109605. JSTOR 2109605.
  2. ^ Diewert, W. Erwin. "An application of the Shephard duality theorem: A generalized Leontief production function." Journal of political economy 79.3 (1971): 481-507.
  3. ^ Up until 1990, the predominant user of this functional form was Iwao Ozaki, a Japanese economist, which explains its namesake. Although much of Ozaki's work remains in Japanese and isn't readily accessible to the general public, there is an exception found in the paper "Economies of Scale and Input-Output Coefficients" within the book "Applications of Input-Output Analysis," edited by A. Carter and A. Brody. This publication is available from North-Holland Publishers, dated 1969, spanning pages 280-302."