Jump to content

Bankruptcy problem

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Erel Segal (talk | contribs) at 11:34, 29 September 2021 (Constrained equal awards). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

The bankruptcy problem,[1] also called the claims problem,[2] is the problem of distributing a homogeneous divisible good (such as money) among people with different claims. The focus is on the case where the amount is insufficient to satisfy all the claims.

The canonical application is a bankrupt firm that is to be liquidated. The firm owes different amounts of money to different creditors, but the total worth of the company's assets is smaller than its total debt. The problem is how to divide the scarce existing money among the creditors.

Another application would be the division of an estate amongst several heirs, particularly when the estate cannot meet all the deceased's commitments.

A third application[2] is tax assessment. One can consider the claimants as taxpayers, the claims as the incomes, and the endowment as the total after-tax income. Determining the allocation of total after-tax income is equivalent to determining the allocation of tax payments.

Definitions

The amount available to divide is denoted by E (=Estate or Endowment). There are n claimants. Each claimant i has a claim denoted by ci.

It is assumed that , that is, the total claims are (weakly) larger than the estate.

A division rule is a function that maps a problem instance to a vector such that and for all i. That is: each claimant receives at most its claim, and the sum of allocations is exactly the estate E.

There are generalized variants in which the total claims might be smaller than the estate. In these generalized variants, is not assumed and is not required.

Rules

There are several rules for solving bankruptcy problems in practice.[1]

Proportional rule

The proportional rule divides the estate proportionally to each agent's claim. Formally, each claimant i receives , where r is a constant chosen such that . We denote the outcome of the proportional rule by .

Examples:

  • . That is: if the estate is worth 100 and the claims are 60 and 90, then , so the first claimant gets 40 and the second claimant gets 60.
  • .
  • .

There is a variant called truncated-claims proportional rule, in which each claim larger than E is truncted to E, and then the proportional rule is activated. That is, it equals , where .[2]

Adjusted proportional rule

The adjusted proportional rule[3] first gives, to each agent i, his minimal right, which is the amount not claimed by the other agents. Formally, . Note that implies .

Then, it revises the claim of agent i to , and the estate to . Note that that .

Finally, it activates the truncated-claims proportional rule, that is, it returns , where .

Examples:

  • . The minimal rights are . The remaining claims are and the remaining estate is ; it is divided equally among the claimants.
  • . The minimal rights are . The remaining claims are and the remaining estate is .
  • . The minimal rights are . The remaining claims are and the remaining estate is .

Constrained equal awards

The constrained equal-awards rule divides the estate equally among the agents, ensuring that nobody gets more than their claim. Formally, each claimant i receives , where r is a constant chosen such that . We denote the outcome of this rule by . Examples:

  • ; here .
  • ; here .

Constrained equal losses

The constrained equal-losses rule divides equally the difference between the aggregate claim and the estate, ensuring that no agent ends up with a negative transfer.

Contested garment rule

Another rule, appearing already in the Babylonian Talmud, is the contested garment rule.[4][5]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Alcalde, José; Peris, Josep E. (2017-02-17). "Equal Awards vs. Equal Losses in Bankruptcy Problems". SSRN.
  2. ^ a b c "Axiomatic and game-theoretic analysis of bankruptcy and taxation problems: a survey". Mathematical Social Sciences. 45 (3): 249–297. 2003-07-01. doi:10.1016/S0165-4896(02)00070-7. ISSN 0165-4896.
  3. ^ Curiel, I. J.; Maschler, M.; Tijs, S. H. (1987-09-01). "Bankruptcy games". Zeitschrift für Operations Research. 31 (5): A143 – A159. doi:10.1007/BF02109593. ISSN 1432-5217.
  4. ^ Dagan, Nir (1996). "New characterizations of old bankruptcy rules". Social Choice and Welfare.
  5. ^ O'Neill, Barry (1982-06-01). "A problem of rights arbitration from the Talmud". Mathematical Social Sciences. 2 (4): 345–371. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(82)90029-4. ISSN 0165-4896.